Research Highlights Article
August 10, 2020
Bound by history
Would requiring incumbents to match their previous best vote share improve our democracy?
Yard signs line a residential street in Dallas.
Trong Nguyen
Competitive political races tend to attract the most press attention, but they are the exception rather than the rule. Far more races feature incumbents who sail to an easy reelection.
Especially during an intensely polarized environment, the inability to seriously challenge entrenched power is a threat to democracy.
In the August issue of the American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, author Hans Gersbach offers a way to make election races more competitive. Forcing incumbents to match or exceed their vote share from previous elections could help level the playing field for disadvantaged challengers and keep seat holders accountable.
Gersbach calls them “history-bound reelections.”
“History-bound reelections are a great new tool for democracy and – in times of sharp political polarization – they might be particularly beneficial,” Gersbach said in an email interview with the AEA.
America’s polarization has been blamed on a variety of factors — gerrymandered districts, racial resentment, economic inequality, and other issues. A big obstacle to changing the system is that most of the people holding power in Washington do not face serious threats to their seats. Office-holders enjoy advantages such as the right to send campaign literature at tax-payers’ expense, as well as generally heightened visibility that comes with their job. In 2018, 91 percent of incumbents were reelected to the US House of Representatives.
The larger issue is that reelection is a crude tool for voters to exercise their control on policy choices, Gersbach said. This paper proposes a modest change that would still be close enough to the existing “majority rule” approach—and that satisfies liberal democracy’s fundamental principles—while also making it more difficult to develop entrenched power.
Gersbach’s “history-bound reelection” model includes the following:
- If a candidate is not the incumbent, a simple majority gets him or her elected.
- Incumbent candidates must attain or surpass the highest percentage of votes they ever obtained for the same office.
- If an incumbent loses, the challenger wins or there is a run-off between the challenger and a new candidate.
The result is putting elected officials in office who are less ideologically strident and more effective at serving their constituents, according to Gersbach.
History-bound reelections are a great new tool for democracy and – in times of sharp political polarization – they might be particularly beneficial.
Hans Gersbach
In theory, an office-holder would have to perform as well as possible in order to maintain a winning vote share. This doesn’t mean that candidates in highly conservative or liberal districts would suddenly become centrists, but they might at least become more moderate.
“For reelected office-holders, this should reduce incentives to indulge in their own ideological preferences or to defend extreme positions,” Gersbach said.
Of course, there may be times when having a moderate representative isn’t in the best interest of voters. Facing a high bar for reelection, an official may be reluctant to take a principled stand on a divisive issue, for instance.
Importantly, this is a system that can be easily tweaked. The threshold could be reduced by some margin relative to the highest score in the past, according to Gersbach. Maybe the rules would be applied only after the first reelection, to reduce the pressure to match a high score too early and to foster far-sightedness.
Also, this approach could be applied beyond politics to any system where candidates run for reelection, such as corporate boards. Wherever it is tried, Gersbach said it is a worthwhile experiment on as large a scale as possible.
♦
“History-bound Reelections” appears in the August issue of the American Economic Journal: Microeconomics.